Response to the NESEA BE Boston 2023 Wednesday Keynote, “Why we Stopped Doing Deep Energy Retrofits”
This was originally published on the NESEA website. A recording of the referenced keynote, “Why we Stopped Doing Deep Energy Retrofits,” can be found here.
The presentation, “Why we Stopped Doing Deep Energy Retrofits” by Rachel White and Brendan Kavanagh of Bygmeister was in the proudest tradition of NESEA. It was thoughtful, grounded in years of experience and data, and demonstrated a commitment to, and the value of, ongoing inquiry and analysis. Most importantly, the presenters demonstrated flexibility, humility, and honesty in being willing to change course if evidence appears to support a conclusion different from their own prior convictions. I was impressed by the thorough and wide-ranging analysis. By all these measures it was a strong presentation and a valuable contribution to the conference.
The conclusions, perhaps not surprisingly, were that spending a whole lot for a DER was not as cost effective as doing something less. It was clear that the savings in energy could not offset the increase in construction cost for aggressive, whole-house retrofits (as defined by the presenters). One compelling argument was a graph showing the effectiveness of dollars spent per kgCO2e reduction in more moderate retrofits vs deep energy retrofits. It looked an awful lot like charts of diminishing returns for insulation— graphs that many of us have been pushing aside for years while we suspend disbelief and “tunnel through the cost barrier”.
Bygmeister says they have “changed their minds” and likely won’t do DER’s anymore, because they are not as cost-effective per kgCO2e kept out of the atmosphere as a moderate retrofit. Perhaps more telling was the statement that, since the termination of a Massachusetts DER pilot with an attached the subsidy, the owners won’t choose them anyway.
In some ways this presentation represents a classic case of what Donella Meadows [environmental scientist and author of Thinking in Systems: A Primer] referred to as Bounded Rationality. Bounded Rationality is the idea that most actors are behaving rationally within the confines of a defined set of boundaries with access to certain (limited) information, even if their behaviors seem irrational or are cumulatively destructive when viewed from a larger context. The arguments set out in this presentation make perfect sense to a design/build firm working with private clients who bear the full cost of construction in a society with artificially cheap energy. But, those conditions are themselves the source of both the original problem and the limitations of the analysis. In a free market economic system with NO appreciable feedback mechanism reflecting the cost of environmental harm, this was a foregone conclusion.
My issue is not with the analysis itself, but rather with the systems boundaries for the analysis. By focusing on the cost-benefit concept in the context of a small business and the family-level economics of a home renovation, Rachel and Brendan draw the systems analysis boundary around that which directly affects their business practice and the owners’ decision. This is a perfectly rational approach in a normal context. But we are not in a normal context. We have blown past our limits, and now, every one of us, in every decision we make (unless we are very careful) pushes us further over the edge and worsens an impending catastrophe.
The problem is that this kind of analysis leaves half of the “cost-benefit” equation completely off the ledger. It speaks of cost to the consumer of better construction, and benefit to the same consumer of savings, but nothing of the cost born by all of humanity and ecology of NOT doing deep energy retrofits, and indeed, deep carbon reductions in every sector. In this crisis, all systems boundaries between us and our world melt away and reveal only one encompassing boundary—the very real limits of the planet.
This is the ultimate example of the rather dog-eared trope of “the tragedy of the commons”. Each and every one of us benefits from air and water, a dependable climate and food production, etc., and yet within the narrow frame of our economic lives, it is always “cost beneficial” to do a little less to protect those commons, or indeed to keep actively harming the commons a little more. Unless the commons are assigned a value, and every economic decision is inclusive of the cost of harm to said commons, “cost benefit” is a one-sided fiction.
In short Rachel and Brendan were applying a cost-benefit analysis for a micro-economic context to make a statement about our industry’s strategic responses to a crisis of the global commons known as the atmosphere. The tool does not fit the task. It is not their fault, really. The entire global system of finance, trade, and industry is still blithely playing by the old rules in the face of global catastrophe. Our economic system is structured such that nothing is deemed worth doing without a high rate of return for the financial class, while it quite intentionally externalizes harm to people and ecology. We Americans love to privatize profit and nationalize the cost of cleaning up the devastation (think superfund sites).
This makes it very hard for any of us small fry, dependent on financial institutions and myriad industrial supply chains to make different decisions. We are all embedded in this system and can do precious little about how value is assessed or how the rules are set. However, continuing the same sort of analysis just plays into this systemic habit.
By the time the economic chickens come home to roost for the financial sector through environmental stresses on the markets, most of what we now hold dear will be seriously disrupted, and for many millions, outright destroyed. We are past the point where standard cost-benefit analysis can meaningfully guide us. If we keep at it, we will soon cross another point—the tipping point—from beyond which there is no return. We are literally cost-benefiting ourselves to death.
The problem still remains, how do we, with virtually no leverage, change our own, and our clients’ assessment of “value”, “cost” and “benefit”?